Article · February 005 Source: RePEc citations 35 reads 4,815 authors


Unit Labour Cost and Productivity in Manufacturing Branches



Yüklə 276,31 Kb.
Pdf görüntüsü
səhifə10/19
tarix22.04.2023
ölçüsü276,31 Kb.
#106670
1   ...   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   ...   19
gd80

4. Unit Labour Cost and Productivity in Manufacturing Branches 
The comparisons of productivity and unit labour cost for the aggregate economy and even for 
a broad sector such as manufacturing, hides important details at industry level. In international trade, 
some countries will develop comparative advantages in particular industries. When productivity and 
labour cost levels differ between industries, this may impact the aggregate comparison of unit labour 
cost even if there are no differences between countries at industry level. 
increase in labour productivity in
the aggregate U.S. economy (about 50% between 1980 and 2003) 
compared to manufacturing (an increase of 250% in labour productivity). 


13
A more detailed comparison of ULC within manufacturing requires consistent measures of 
output, compensation and labour input for individual industries. These are available for a more limited 
number of countries. By way of illustration, tables 1 to 3 show a breakdown of total manufacturing 
into seven major industry groups for labour productivity (table 1), labour compensation (table 2) and 
unit labour cost (table 3) for three major European countries (France, Germany and the UK) relative 
to the United States from 1980 to 2003.
17
Table 1
shows that the German and French manufacturing sectors show a substantial erosion 
of productivity levels relative to the U.S.. Much of the widening of the manufacturing productivity 
gap between these countries is due to the much smaller share of ICT-producing industries in the 
European countries. The industries producing products in the area of information technology (IT) 
hardware and communication (C) equipment have shown by far the faster productivity growth rates, 
in particular since the 1990s.
18
In addition to machinery and equipment, German manufacturing also shows a widening of the 
productivity gap in textiles and chemicals, but an improvement relative to the U.S. in food, beverages 
and tobacco and “other manufacturing industries”. As for the aggregate figures discussed in section 3, 
the relative levels of wage compensation in 
Table 2
are strongly affected by the change in the 
nominal exchange rate. The depreciation of the euro between 1995 and 2000 has led to a strong 
decline in relative wage rates across the board. But in 2000 relative labour cost in German textiles was 
still higher than in the U.S., whereas relative labour cost were lowest by far in the food manufacturing 
industry. 
Table 3
shows that in 2003, German ULC levels were clearly lower than those in the U.S. in 
food manufacturing, chemicals and other manufacturing, but not in textiles, metal products, and ICT 
and non-ICT machinery. 
The comparative productivity results for the manufacturing sector in France are also quite 
large, but in all sectors except ICT machinery, the levels are above those in Germany. As for 
Germany, the improved performance of the food sector and other manufacturing is also found for 
France, but – in contrast to Germany – French productivity levels in non-ICT machinery improved 
relative to the U.S. as well. Moreover the widening of the productivity gap in French manufacturing 
relative to the U.S. since 1995 is not as big as in Germany. With the exception of non-ICT machinery, 
relative labour costs were also slightly higher in France than in Germany, but the difference was not 
as big as for productivity. At the aggregate level, labour cost in France stayed just below that of 
Germany. As a result relative unit labour cost levels in France were at or below the German levels for 
all sectors (except ICT machinery) and for total manufacturing. Compared to the U.S. ULC levels 
were higher in France for textiles and ICT machinery. 
17
See van Ark (1995, 1996) for similar measures for the period 1970 to 1990. 
18
It should be stressed that actual comparative levels are affected by the choice of the benchmark PPP, 
which is 1997 in this study. The relative level might be different if PPPs for, for example, 2002 would be used 
as the benchmark PPP, because the weights will be different between industries. The further a year is away from 
the benchmark year, the more likely it is that the relative level is distorted by the weights of the benchmark year. 
But unlike the actual comparative levels, the change in relative levels will remain unchanged irrespective of the 
choice of the benchmark PPP.



Yüklə 276,31 Kb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   ...   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   ...   19




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©genderi.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

    Ana səhifə