Coase (1937): To understand firms, we must understand why markets/contracts are costly. Coase (1937): To understand firms, we must understand why markets/contracts are costly



Yüklə 173,5 Kb.
tarix15.08.2018
ölçüsü173,5 Kb.
#62882



Coase (1937): To understand firms, we must understand why markets/contracts are costly.

  • Coase (1937): To understand firms, we must understand why markets/contracts are costly.

  • What are these costs?

  • Williamson (1971), Klein, Crawford and Alchian (1978): Relationship-specific investments cause lock-in. Long-term contracts incomplete. Under non-integration, quasi-rents dissipated in ex post bargaining. Integration avoids this.



No formal model here. A formal model is provided in Grossman and Hart (1986), Hart and Moore (1990). In GHM, contracts incomplete, but renegotiation a la Coase (1960) leads to ex post efficiency. However, as a result of hold-up, non-contractible ex ante investments are distorted. Allocation of residual control rights/asset ownership can mitigate this distortion. Leads to a theory of optimal asset ownership/firm boundaries.

  • No formal model here. A formal model is provided in Grossman and Hart (1986), Hart and Moore (1990). In GHM, contracts incomplete, but renegotiation a la Coase (1960) leads to ex post efficiency. However, as a result of hold-up, non-contractible ex ante investments are distorted. Allocation of residual control rights/asset ownership can mitigate this distortion. Leads to a theory of optimal asset ownership/firm boundaries.

  • Weaknesses: not very helpful for internal organization of large firms.



Basic idea: an ex ante contract negotiated under (relatively) competitive conditions shapes parties’ entitlements regarding ex post outcomes.

  • Basic idea: an ex ante contract negotiated under (relatively) competitive conditions shapes parties’ entitlements regarding ex post outcomes.

  • A party compares the ex post outcome to other outcomes permitted by the contract, and if he does not get what he feels entitled to, he is aggrieved and shades on non-contractible aspects of performance.

  • Shading does not (significantly) affect own payoff but does significantly affect other party’s payoff. Shading=> deadweight losses.



Leads to tradeoff between contractual flexibility and rigidity. A flexible contract is good in that parties can adjust to the (observable but unverifiable) state of the world but bad in that there is a lot of aggrievement and shading. A rigid contract is good in that there is little aggrievement and shading but bad in that the parties cannot adjust to the state of the world.

  • Leads to tradeoff between contractual flexibility and rigidity. A flexible contract is good in that parties can adjust to the (observable but unverifiable) state of the world but bad in that there is a lot of aggrievement and shading. A rigid contract is good in that there is little aggrievement and shading but bad in that the parties cannot adjust to the state of the world.

  • Two new ingredients: Ex post trade is only partially contractible, and behavioral elements affect performance.



Simplified version of Hart and Moore (2008), Section III

  • Simplified version of Hart and Moore (2008), Section III

  • Buyer B/Seller S

  • B’s value v = 20



Assume:

  • Assume:

  • Trade is voluntary ex post (e.g., because third parties cannot verify why trade didn’t occur).

  • S’s cost is observed by both parties ex post but is not verifiable.

  • Only S can shade. S feels entitled to best outcome permitted by the contract and shades to point where B’s payoff falls by θ times the difference between S’s ideal payoff and what S actually receives.



There are many sellers relative to buyers at date 0, i.e., B has all the bargaining power at date 0 and chooses date 0 contract.

  • There are many sellers relative to buyers at date 0, i.e., B has all the bargaining power at date 0 and chooses date 0 contract.

  • No lump-sum transfers (e.g., because S is wealth-constrained).

  • Parties are risk-neutral.

  • No renegotiation.

  • Note: (3)-(5) are not assumed in Hart and Moore (2008). (7) is relaxed in Hart (2009).



Parties agree ex ante on price range [10, 16]. B chooses the trading price p from this range ex post.

  • Parties agree ex ante on price range [10, 16]. B chooses the trading price p from this range ex post.

  • In high-cost state, B chooses p = 16. B’s payoff = 4; S’s payoff = 0.

  • In low-cost state, B chooses p = 10. B’s payoff = 10-6θ; S’s payoff = 0.

  • Expected surplus W = 4π+(10-6θ)(1-π).



Parties agree ex ante that p = 10.

  • Parties agree ex ante that p = 10.

  • In high-cost state, no trade.

  • In low-cost state, B’s payoff = 10; S’s payoff = 0.

  • W = 10(1-π).



Rigid contract will be chosen if π is small enough, even though it leads to ex post inefficiency with positive probability.

  • Rigid contract will be chosen if π is small enough, even though it leads to ex post inefficiency with positive probability.

  • More shading will occur if the flexible contract is chosen than if the rigid contract is chosen.

  • Fehr, Hart and Zehnder (2008) find support for implications (1) and (2) in an experiment.

  • Outside options matter in this world even if they are “dominated,” given that trade does not always occur. Thus, asset ownership will matter for reasons different from GHM (there are no ex ante investments). For details, see Hart (2009).

  • Model consistent with empirical evidence showing that uncertainty makes economic relationships hard to manage. See Goetz and Scott(1983)…..Masten(2007).



Based on Hart and Moore (2008), Section IV

  • Based on Hart and Moore (2008), Section IV

  • 2 tasks. Symmetric uncertainty such that not known in advance which task is better. Who should choose the task? (Hart and Moore (2008) also consider the possibility that the task should be fixed in advance.)

  • Assume both parties can shade now.



Optimal to fix price and let B choose task (W = 10-2θ), rather than letting S choose task (W = 6-6θ).

  • Optimal to fix price and let B choose task (W = 10-2θ), rather than letting S choose task (W = 6-6θ).

  • Why fix price?



Now it’s optimal to fix price and let S choose task (W = 12-6θ), rather than letting B choose task (W = 10-8θ).

  • Now it’s optimal to fix price and let S choose task (W = 12-6θ), rather than letting B choose task (W = 10-8θ).

  • Remark: Can throw light on choice between employment and independent contracting. Cf. Simon (1951).





Each unit is owned by its manager/employee (nonintegration).

  • Each unit is owned by its manager/employee (nonintegration).

  • Then coordination won’t occur since unit 2 will veto.

  • This is inefficient since 20-10 + 20-10 < 14-8 + 14-2.

  • B) Units owned together by an outsider (integration).

  • Coordination will occur since 20+20 -10θ >28



However, if we change the (14, 2) payoff to (14, -1), then integration may result in coordination even though this is inefficient (if 40-13θ >28). In this case, nonintegration is better.

  • However, if we change the (14, 2) payoff to (14, -1), then integration may result in coordination even though this is inefficient (if 40-13θ >28). In this case, nonintegration is better.



Formal models of asset ownership and firm boundaries (“property rights theories”) have to date focused on ex ante investment inefficiencies. Ex post trade is always efficient as a result of Coasian bargaining. This is restrictive.

  • Formal models of asset ownership and firm boundaries (“property rights theories”) have to date focused on ex ante investment inefficiencies. Ex post trade is always efficient as a result of Coasian bargaining. This is restrictive.

  • “Contracts As Reference Points” broadens the scope of the theory by incorporating ex post inefficiency. I believe that this approach can explain why uncertainty makes economic relationships hard to manage, has new implications for asset ownership and firm boundaries, and may be helpful for going “inside the firm” (on the last, see Hart and Holmstrom (2010)).



Needless to say, the approach relies on some strong and nonstandard assumptions. One encouraging sign is that some of those assumptions receive support in experiments, but much more needs to be done to test their validity and robustness.

  • Needless to say, the approach relies on some strong and nonstandard assumptions. One encouraging sign is that some of those assumptions receive support in experiments, but much more needs to be done to test their validity and robustness.



Yüklə 173,5 Kb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©genderi.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

    Ana səhifə