Article · February 005 Source: RePEc citations 35 reads 4,815 authors



Yüklə 276,31 Kb.
Pdf görüntüsü
səhifə4/19
tarix22.04.2023
ölçüsü276,31 Kb.
#106670
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   ...   19
gd80

numerator
, which reflects the 
labour cost component of the equation, is typically expressed in nominal terms, whereas the 
denominator
, which is output or productivity, is measured in real or volume terms. This implies that, 
when comparing unit labour cost levels across countries, the level of wages or labour compensation is 
converted at the official exchange rate: it represents the cost element of the arbitrage across countries. 
In contrast, output or productivity relates to a 
volume
measure as it resembles a 
quantity unit
of 
5 See OECD Economic Outlook. Sources and Methods http://www.oecd.org/eco/sources-and-methods). See 
also Durand et al. (1998). 
6 See IMF, World Economic Outlook, Statistical Appendix
(http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/weorepts.htm). See also Turner and Golub (1997). 
7 For a comprehensive overview of price and cost competitiveness measures see, for example, Turner and Van 
‘t Dack (1993). 


4
output. Hence for level comparisons output needs to be converted to a common currency using a 
purchasing power parity instead of the exchange rate, so that comparative output levels are adjusted 
for differences in relative prices across countries. 
Hence the unit labour measure represents the current cost of labour per “quantity unit” of 
output produced. For an analysis in terms of comparative levels between countries A and B this 
implies:
8
ULC
AB
= [(LC
A
/ER
AB
)/LC
B
] / (Y
A
/PPP
AB
)/Y
A

where ULC stands for unit labour cost, LC for total labour compensation, Y for total output 
(or value added), ER
AB
for the official nominal exchange rate between countries A and B and PPP
AB
for the purchasing power parity for output in country A relative to country B. Dividing labour 
compensation and output by employment or total hours worked, gives the labour cost per labour unit 
(lc) and labour productivity (y): 
ULC
AB
= [(lc
A
/ER
AB
)/lc
B
] / (y
A
/PPP
AB
)/y
A

Equation (2) can be rewritten to decompose the difference in unit labour cost between country 
A and country B into three components, i.e., the difference in nominal labour cost per person, the 
difference in nominal labour productivity (that is unadjusted for differences in price levels) and the 
differences in relative price levels: 
log (ULC
A
– ULC
B
)= log (lc
A
/ER
AB
– lc
B
) – log (y
A
/ER
AB
– y
B
)
– log (ER
AB
- PPP
AB

All these components contribute in their own way to differences in cost competitiveness 
between the two countries, and will be discussed in more detail below. 
Unit labour costs are most easily measured and best understood for tradable sectors of the 
economy, in particular for the manufacturing sector which produces most internationally tradable 
products. The unit labour cost measure, however, is also useful for analysis at the level of the 
aggregate economy. However, the precise interpretation of a change in ULC or a difference in ULC 
levels across countries always depends on the source from which the change originates. For example, 
an increase in labour costs can result from upward wage pressure or from a slowdown in productivity 
growth. The upward wage pressure may be largely an external phenomenon triggered by an 
appreciation of a country’s currency, or it may have a domestic cause due to, for example, a shortage 
on the labour market. A productivity slowdown may be caused, for example, by a rise in the sectoral 
share of services sector, as seen in many developed (industrialized) countries. Services productivity 
usually grows more slowly than manufacturing productivity, whereas the development of labour cost 
8
In this paper levels are compared for each individual country with the United States only. But countries may be 
compared between each other through the U.S.. The use of trade-weighted ULC levels indices is an issue for 
future work. In terms of growth rates, the change in unit labour cost can be written as 

ULC = 

LC / [

Y/

P] 
where P stands for the price of output, and the symbol 

indicates the change over time. 


5
is often less diverse across sectors. But slow productivity growth may also be due to lack of 
technological progress or slow reforms in product and labour markets. The causes of the changes in 
unit labour costs, therefore, have important implications for labour and product market policies, 
technologies and innovation policies as well as foreign trade policies.
Before returning to the more direct use of ULC measures for tradable sectors, it should be 
stressed that a change in unit labour cost in the non-tradable sector also impacts the tradable sector, in 
particular when non-tradable products or services are used as an input by the tradable sector. 
Moreover, many service industries are becoming more tradable themselves, which is an indication 
that the distinction between tradable and non-tradable sectors of the economy is becoming 
increasingly anachronistic. An exclusive focus on unit labour cost in the manufacturing industry may 
therefore be a too restrictive approach to study competitiveness. 
Even for tradables, the ULC index should not be interpreted as a comprehensive measure of 
competitiveness for several reasons. Firstly, ULC measures deal exclusively with the cost of 
labour

Even though labour costs account for the major share of inputs, the cost of capital and intermediate 
inputs can also be crucial factors for comparisons of cost competitiveness between countries.
9
Secondly, the measure reflects only 
cost
competitiveness. In the case of durable consumer and 
investment goods, for example, competitiveness is also determined by other factors than costs, 
notably by technological and social capabilities and by demand factors. Improvements in product 
quality, customization or improved after-sales services are not necessarily reflected in lower ULC. In 
the literature on competitiveness inspired by Michael Porter, attention is given not only to factor 
inputs, but also to demand conditions, the presence of local suppliers and clusters, and an environment 
that encourages investment, innovation and competition.
10
Thirdly, measures of cost competitiveness 
may be distorted by the effects from, for example, bilateral market access agreements, direct and 
indirect export subsidies and tariff protection.
Unit labour cost measures also do not have the same coverage as some of the broader 
composite competitiveness indicators which have gained much popularity in recent years. These 
broader indicators include measures of economic performance, innovative capacity, structural change, 
improved living standards and social conditions. Selections of such indicators are taken on board in 
composite indicators such as, for example, the “World Competitiveness Index” of the International 
Institute for Management Development (IMD), the “Growth and Business Competitiveness Indexes” 
of the World Economic Forum (WEF), the “Structural Indicators” of the European Union and the 
“Human Development Index” of the United Nations. Individual countries, such as Ireland, Japan, the 
United Kingdom and the United States also developed their own competitiveness indicators. Although 
such indicators are more comprehensive than the unit labour cost measures used here, the individual 
components address very different aspects of the competitiveness process and an aggregation into one 
composite indicator may therefore be very sensitive to the underlying components used in the index. 
9
One might argue that with greater international tradability of capital and intermediate inputs, labour input is 
the key determinant of cost competitiveness as it is much less mobile across countries. 
10
See Porter (1990). See also Fagerberg et al. (2005). 


6

Yüklə 276,31 Kb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   ...   19




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©genderi.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

    Ana səhifə