How Inclusive Is Abenomics?; by Chie Aoyagi, Giovanni Ganelli, and Kentaro Murayama; imf working Paper No. 15/54; March 1, 2015



Yüklə 295,74 Kb.
Pdf görüntüsü
səhifə11/11
tarix23.11.2017
ölçüsü295,74 Kb.
#12180
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   10   11

 28 

and solving for x, we can show that the maximum effect reached at the inflation level of 

1.586/0.706 = 2.246 %; and the maximum value would be 1.781%. 

 

 



The marginal effect of inflation depends on the initial value: 

 

 



1.586

–  0.353


1.586

–  0.353


 

In the text chart, we plot the marginal effect of changes in inflation rates (red line), while 

assuming an initial inflation rate of 0.00% as in our policy scenario. The chart shows an 

initially increasing, but then 

diminishing marginal effect. 

Moreover, the marginal effect 

becomes negative (i..e further 

inflation reduces inclusive growth) 

at around 4.5%. Note that, because 

the specified curve is symmetric, the 

marginal effect would decay off at 

the same distance from the optimal 

level. In this case, it is 

2.246


 2.246

0    4.492%. 

 

The policy scenario we considered is 



the initial value of 0.00% and the 

targe rate of 2.00% (text chart, green 

line). With an increase of 2.00% 

points, the marginal effect on the 

inclusive growth is 1.76%, slighlty 

less than the value at the optimal level. 

 

 

 




 29 

Appendix D. Causality Direction between Inflation and Growth  

 

To test endogeneity, we run simple bilateral regressions between growth and inflation: 



y

a y


a y


b m


b m


μ v  


 

where   is the dependent variable and   is the (supposedly endogenous) explanatory 

variables. Note that this is not equivalent to a conventional Grange causilitu test because: the 

lag is not chosen by statistical significance, but limited by the data availability (l=2);  

regressions are run separately; and the specification contains the fixed effect for each 

prefecture.  

 

The result is shown in the table below.  



Dependent variable: 

Growth 


Inflation 

(1) 


(2) 

lag(dys, 1) 

-0.461

***


 

0.080


**

 

(0.110) 



(0.039) 

lag(dys, 2) 

-0.078 

0.094


**

 

(0.104) 



(0.037) 

lag(Inflation, 1) 

2.052

***


 

0.962


***

 

(0.251) 



(0.090) 

lag(Inflation, 2) 

1.431

***


 

0.816


***

 

(0.093) 



(0.033) 

Observations 

144 

144 


R

2

 



0.748 

0.918 


Adjusted R

2

 



0.478 

0.587 


F Statistic (df = 4; 92) 68.230

***


 

258.300


***

 

Note: 

*

p<0.1; 


**

p<0.05; 


***

p<0.01 


 

Both variables are good leading indicator of the other both at the lag of 1 and 2, but the 

coefficients on the impact of inflation on growth tend to be larger than those of the impact on 

griwth on inflation.  

 

 



 30 

We have also estimated the same model as in the becnhamrk case, btu with with lagged (l=1) 

inflation (5 year averages) as an instrument variable (Balestra & Varadharajan-

Krishnakumar, 1987). The results are shown below, and are broadly consistens with those 

discussed in the main text. 

 

Table 1 



Results for All Income, IV 

Dependent variable: 

dys 


dy 

dw 


(1) 

(2) 


(3) 

Inflation (%) 

4.707

***


4.592

***


0.051 

(1.154)  (1.071)  (0.259)

Inflation, squared 

-0.876


***

-0.832


***

-0.034 


(0.195)  (0.181)  (0.044)

Part- to Full-time job opennings (%) 0.031 

0.023 

0.007 


(0.038)  (0.035)  (0.009)

Female labor force participation (%) 0.270

*

  0.225


*

  0.042 


(0.137)  (0.127)  (0.031)

Labor input growth (%) 

0.156 

0.136 


0.019 

(0.291)  (0.270)  (0.065)

Initial GDP per capita 

-5.476


***

-4.737


***

-0.707


*

(1.812)  (1.683)  (0.407)

Elderly index 

0.450


***

0.429


***

0.014 


(0.153)  (0.142)  (0.034)

Observations 

235 

235 


235 

R

2



 

0.486 


0.539 

0.105 


Adjusted R

2

 



0.374 

0.415 


0.081 

F Statistic (df = 7; 181) 

5.173

***


7.330

***


3.021

***


Not

e: 

*

p<0.1; 



**

p<0.05; 


***

p<0.01 



 31 

Results for Working-age Income, IV

Dependent variable: 

dys.work dy.work dw.work

(1) 

(2) 


(3) 

Inflation (%) 

4.926

***


  4.371

***


0.534 

(1.226)  (1.047)  (0.324) 

Inflation, squared 

-0.852


***

-0.743


***

-0.106


*

 

(0.207)  (0.177)  (0.055) 



Part- to Full-time job opennings (%) 0.025 

0.014 


0.011 

(0.040)  (0.034)  (0.011) 

Female labor force participation (%) 0.338

**

  0.250



**

  0.088


**

 

(0.146)  (0.124)  (0.038) 



Labor input growth (%) 

-0.020 


0.018 

-0.039 


(0.309)  (0.264)  (0.082) 

Initial GDP per capita 

-4.770

**

  -3.545



**

-1.230


**

(1.926)  (1.645)  (0.509) 

Elderly index 

0.497


***

  0.417


***

0.079


*

 

(0.162)  (0.139)  (0.043) 



Observations 

235 


235 

235 


R

2

 



0.444 

0.514 


0.007 

Adjusted R

2

 

0.342 



0.396 

0.005 


F Statistic (df = 7; 181) 

-0.283 


5.466

***


-4.416 

Note: 

*

p<0.1; 



**

p<0.05; 


***

p<0.01


 

 

 



 


 32 

Appendix E. Contributions of regressors to variation in equity.  

 

In the text table below me represent various measures of how much of the variation in the 

equity index is explained by the various regressors. The top three variables for each measure 

are denoted by ***. 

 

Standardized Regression Coefficients show the expected change of the dependent variable in 



standard deviations with respect to one standard deviation change in the explanatory variable. 

(e.g. one standard deviation change in FLP is associated with a 0.373 standard deviation 

change in equity index growth).  

Semi-Partial Correlation Coefficients measure the unique contribution of each explanatory 

variable in explaining the variations of the dependent variable. The proportion of the 

variation that is jointly explained by multiple variables is not accounted for in this measure 

(i.e. if all the explanatory variables are independent of each other, the set of semi-partial 

correlation coefficients sum up to the R^2 of the model.) 

Extra Sum of Squares is simply the amount of sum of squared residuals reduced by removing 

one variable from the full model. (e.g. by removing inflation the sum of squared residuals is 

increased by 0.707, by removing inflations squared it is increase by 0.321). Note that they do 

not sum up to the total sum of squared residuals. 

 

Contributions of regressors to variation in equity. 



  

Standardized 

Regression 

Coefficients 

Semi-Partial 

Correlation 

Coefficients 

Extra Sum 

of Squares 

Inflation 

-0.089 0.005*** 

0.707*** 

Inflation, squared 

-0.056 0.006*** 

0.321*** 

Job Openings 

0.132*** 0.001  0.089 

FLP 


0.373*** 0.007***  0.254 

Labor Growth 

0.069 0.0005 

0.032 


GDP PC 

-0.58*** 0.004 

0.757*** 

Elderly Index 

0.079 0.0001 

0.017 


  

- 0.0236 

 

 



 

 

 



 

 

 



 


 33 

 

R



EFERENCES

 

 

Ali, I., and Son, H. H. (2007). Measuring Inclusive Growth. Asian Development Review, 



24(1), 11-31. 

 

Anand, R., Mishra, S., and Peiris, S. J. (2013). Inclusive Growth: Measurement and 



Determinants. IMF Working Paper, WP/13/135. 

 

Aoyagi, C., and Ganelli, G. (2013). The Path to Higher Growth: Does Revamping the 



Japanese Labor Market Matter?. IMF Working Paper, WP/13/202. Forthcoming in 

Economic Systems

 

Baba, N., and Tanaka, Y. (2014, October 10). Growing Disparities in Consumer Sentiment 



by Income Bracket. Japan Economics Analyst

 

Balestra, P., and Varadharajan-Krishnakumar, J. (1987). Full Information Estimations of a 



System of Simultaneous Equations With Error Components. Econometric Theory

223-246. 

 

Baltagi, B. H. (2013). Econometric Analysis of Panel Data (Fifth ed.). West Sussex, United 



Kingdom: John Wiley & Sons Ltd. 

 

Baruah, J. (2012). Inclusive Growth under India's Neo-liberal Regime: Towards an 



Exposition. MPRA Working Paper

 

Berg, A. G., and Ostry, J. D. (2011). Inequality and Unsustainable Growth: Two Sides of. 



IMF Staff Discussion Note, SDN/11/08

 

Cabinet Office, Government of Japan. (2014, 8 29). Retrieved 8 29, 2014, from 



http://www8.cao.go.jp/kodomonohinkon/index.html#taikou 

 

Grammy, Abbas, and Djeto Assane (2006). The poverty-growth-inequality triangle 



hypothesis: An empirical examination. Journal of Policy Modeling. 

 

Hausman, J. (1978). Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica, 46, 1251-1271. 



 

Heckman, J. J. (2000). Policies to foster human capital. Research in Economics

 

Honda, Y. (1985). Testing the Error Components Model With Non-Normal Disturbances. 



Review of Economic Studies, 52, 681-690. 

 



 34 

IMF. (2013). The Managing Director's Global Policy Agenda. International Monetary Fund. 

(2013, 12 12). IMF Agenda to Focus on Strong, Balanced, and Inclusive Growth.  

 

J.A., Hausman. (1978). Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica,, 1251-1271. 



 

Japan Revitalization Strategy Council, Cabinet. (2014). Policy note on the Evolution of 



Growth Strategies. Cabinet, Japan. Retrieved from 

http://www.kantei.go.jp/jp/singi/keizaisaisei/pdf/housin_honbun_140120.pdf 

 

Jones, R. S. (2007). Income Inequality, Poverty and Social Spending in Japan. OECD 



Economic Department Working Papers, No. 556. doi:doi: 10.1787/177754708811 

 

Kakwani, N. (1980). On a class of poverty measures. Econometrica, 48, 437-446. 



 

Kennedy, W. J., and Gentle, J. E. (1980). Statistical computing. New York. 

 

Khan, M. S., and Senhadji, A. S. (2000). Threshold Effect in the Relationship Between 



Inflation and Growth. IMF Working Paper 00/110

 

Klasen, S. (2010). Measuring and Monitoring Inclusive Growth: Multiple Definitions, Open 



Questions, and some Constructive Proposals. ADB Sustainable Development Working 

Paper Series

 

Kleiber, C. (2005). The Lorenz Curve in Economics and Econometrics. Gini-Lorenz 



Centennial Conference, (p. 20). Siena. 

 

Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. The American economic 



review, 1-28. 

 

Nihon-Keizai Shinbun. (2004, 8 29). NIKKEI (Nihon-Keizai Shinbun). Retrieved August 29, 



2014, from http://www.nikkei.com/article/DGXLASDG28H10_Z20C14A8CC0000/ 

 

OECD. (2011). An Overview of Growing Income Inequalities in OECD Countries: Main 



Findings. OECD. 

 

OECD. (2011). Divided We Stand: Why Inequality Keeps Rising. OECD Publisher. Retrieved 



from http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/social-issues-migration-health/the-causes-of-

growing-inequalities-in-oecd-countries_9789264119536-en 

 

OECD. (2014). JAPAN: Advancing the third arrow for a resilient economy and inclusive 



growth. "Better Policies" Series


 35 

Ostry, J. D., and Berg, A. (2011). Inequality and unsustainable growth: two sides of the same 

coin? IMF Working Paper, No. 11/08

 

Otsuki, T. A. (1978). An Aspect of the Size Distribution of Income in Prewar Japan.  



 

Ravallion, M., and Datt, G. (1992). Growth and Redistribution Components of Changes in 

Poverty Measures: A Decomposition with Applications to Brazil and India in the 

1980s. Journal of Development Economics, 38, 275-295. 

 

Shorrocks, A. (1983). Ranking income distributions. Economica, 50, 3-17. 



 

Solow, R. M. (1956). A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The quarterly journal 



of economics, 65-94. 

 

Steinberg, C., and Nakane, M. (2012). Can Women Save Japan? IMF Working Paper, 



WP12/248

 

The World Bank. (2014). World Development Indicators. Washington, DC. 



 

Thistle, P. D. (1989). Duality between generalized Lorenz curves and distribution functions. 



Economic Studies Quarterly, 40, 183-187. 

 

Thistle, P. D. (1989). Ranking distributions with generalized Lorenz curves. Southern 



Economic Journal, 56, 1-12. 

 

UN System Task Team. (2012). Macroeconomic stability, inclusive growth and employment. 



ILO, UNCTAD, UNDESA, WTO. 

 

UN System Task Team. (2012). Macroeconomic Stability, Inclusive Growth and 



Employment.  

 

Yüklə 295,74 Kb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   2   3   4   5   6   7   8   9   10   11




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©genderi.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

    Ana səhifə